On the equity market, one well known feature of a malfunctioning emerging market is the domination of the market index. When the equity market works badly, there is poor disclosure about companies, so day-to-day changes in stock prices based on information revelation by companies take place to a limited extent. In badly structured countries, the dominant risk that a company faces is caused by macroeconomics and politics. As an extreme example, the dominant question in Sri Lanka has been about the war. The day-to-day fluctuations of stock prices are primarily about the outlook on Prabhakaran, they have relatively little to do with information about one company at a time.
In such a malfunctioning emerging equity market, the fluctuations of individual stocks are relatively unimportant, and all that matters is the fluctuation of the stock market index. In international comparisons of this issue, India fares well. In India, Nifty accounts for a proportion of the fluctuation of (say) Jet Airways or (say) Sundaram Fasteners, which is relatively small. India looks more like an OECD country in this respect. This reflects the sophistication of the Indian equity market, which (in turn) reflects the correct decisions made in economic policy by MOF and Sebi from 1992 onwards.
Similar logic applies to the bond market. In a sophisticated bond market, the short-term interest rate and the long-term interest rate have complex reasoning of their own. They do not necessarily move in tandem. There is a liquid market for each of them, complete with analytical ideas, speculators and arbitrageurs. As an example, Figure 1 superposes the 90-day and the 10-year interest rate in the US. It shows substantial movements of the 90-day rate, which differ from the movements of the 10-year rate.
We turn to India in Figure 2. This graph also superposes the 90-day rate with the 10-year rate. The scale of the x and y axes of both graphs are identical, to facilitate comparison. The first point we see is that there is a secular gap in interest rates. India has high interest rates, ranging from 3% to 12%. This reflects the lack of a proper institutional foundation of a central bank. As an example, RBI continues to argue that the accountability mechanism of inflation targeting should not come about in India. There is a simmering conflict in India between politicians (who desire low inflation) versus RBI (which enjoys avoiding accountability). Most modern economists would side with the politicians on this one.
The second interesting feature is the extent to which the two rates move together. There are sharp fluctuations in interest rates. Interest rate risk is a real problem in India. Every borrower or lender faces substantial risk because these rates can change quite sharply in a short time. At the same time, both rates tend to move together strongly.
This reflects the pathology of a malfunctioning emerging market. There is not much in India by way of analytical work, speculation and arbitrage on the bond market. The short rate and the long rate do not have much of a life of their own. There is really only one macro shock which takes place each day, which moves both rates. This is akin to being in Sri Lanka in the stock market, where there isn?t much price discovery about individual stocks every day; instead there is just overall politics/macroeconomics hitting the market index.
RBI has made important mistakes in a pair of committee reports. The first committee report forced the use of physical settlement, claiming that cash settled interest rate futures are infeasible. This reflected a lack of knowledge of standard finance textbooks, which teach how to deal with cash settled interest rate derivatives. RBI went on to then block futures on short-term interest rates (as recommended by the first committee).
These are mistakes of policy, which work to impede India?s economic growth. In the long run, RBI has to solve the human resource and incentive problems that are persistently leading to such mistakes. In the short term, the economy has to now make the best of what it has got.
Owing to numerous efforts by RBI at preventing a bond market from coming about, there is not much by way of price discovery of a short bond as opposed to the long bond. There is certain irony in observing that as a consequence, the damage that is done by the most recent mistakes is reduced. All that happens on the bond market is one big question every day: ?What is the interest rate?. In such a world, 10-year bond futures alone can be rather useful.
?The author is an economist with interests in finance, pensions and macroeconomics